
1. Inject Equity by EXISTING Shareholders
- Increases equity
- Improves capital structure; ๐ท๐๐๐ก/๐ธ๐๐ข๐๐ก๐ฆ ratio reduces

2. Inject NEW MINORITY Equity
- Increases equity by new Shareholders
- Existing Shareholders are diluted but still in control
- Initial Public Offering (IPO)
- Improves capital structure; ๐ท๐๐๐ก/๐ธ๐๐ข๐๐ก๐ฆ ratio improves

3. Inject NEW MAJORITY Equity
- Increases equity by new Shareholders
- Existing Shareholders are diluted; control passes to New Shareholders
- IPO
- Improves capital structure; ๐ท๐๐๐ก/๐ธ๐๐ข๐๐ก๐ฆ ratio improves

4. Sell NON-PRODUCTIVE Assets
- Scale down balance sheet by selling non-productive assets
- Sale proceeds to reduce debt
- Improves capital structure; ๐ท๐๐๐ก/๐ธ๐๐ข๐๐ก๐ฆ ratio improves

5. Liquidate ALL Assets
- Orderly winding down to maximize realisable value of assets => soft landing
- Sale proceeds repay debt in priority over equity

Alternate source of equity injection
Improve Adjusted Working Capital
- Re-invest
- Repay Debt

Stress Testing the 5-Step Capital Solutions Under Distress
Letโs stress test this 5-step capital solution sequence together.
At first glance, itโs logical on a spectrum from preservation to surrender of control, but to refine it, let’s examine:
1๏ธโฃ Is it consistent with first principles?
Whatโs the core problem?
- A company with diminishing market equity faces capital scarcity, loss of confidence, and shrinking capacity to raise funds.
- The first-principles objective is to bridge the capital gap while preserving value for current stakeholdersโunless forced to surrender.
The two hard constraints:
- Numerator problem: Shrinking earnings/cash flow leading to lower valuation multiples.
- Denominator problem: Fixed obligations (debt, operational costs) require capital solutions to avoid insolvency.
2๏ธโฃ Letโs map the 5 steps into a capital structure intervention hierarchy:
Step | Action | First Principles Goal |
---|---|---|
1 | Existing shareholders inject equity | Preserve current ownership, prevent dilution |
2 | Seek new minority shareholders | Bring in fresh capital but still avoid change-of-control |
3 | Bring in majority shareholder | Accept change-of-control (M&A, strategic investor, white knight) |
4 | Restructure assets (sell non-productive assets) | Shrink the denominator, improve capital efficiency |
5 | Liquidation | Last resort: break-up value realization |
3๏ธโฃ What frameworks are implicit here?
Capital Waterfall for Distressed Equity:
Level | Source of Solution | Nature of Impact |
---|---|---|
Equity Recapitalization | Steps 1-3 | Shift in control and ownership |
Operational Restructuring | Step 4 | Improve asset productivity, free up cash |
Terminal Solution | Step 5 | Value realization via liquidation |
4๏ธโฃ Are the steps logically sequenced?
Mostly yesโbut consider two challenges:
Challenge A: Are steps 1โ3 really sequential?
In practice, they compete, not sequence. Why?
- Existing shareholders (Step 1) often refuse to inject more funds if the business model is broken.
- New investors (Step 2/3) may only participate if they can get control or significant influenceโso Steps 2 & 3 blur quickly.
Counterpoint:
You may want to model this as a branching decision tree, not a linear path.
Challenge B: Why sell only non-productive assets in Step 4?
- In distress, non-core assets are often easier to sell at fair value than “non-productive assets” (which may be unsellable or heavily discounted).
- First-principles logic would say:
- Sell non-core assets first (even if productive, but less critical to survival)
- Then sell non-productive assets (but accept they may fetch poor prices).
So the distinction between non-productive and non-core may be too rigid. The real axis is “cash-generation vs strategic value vs marketability.”
5๏ธโฃ Can this be a model or tool?
Yes, but to be more robust and transferable, consider framing it as a Capital Control Spectrum or Capital Salvage Model, not just steps.
Capital Salvage Model
Zone | Action | Control Impact | Capital Raised |
---|---|---|---|
Preserve | Shareholder rights issue | Minimal dilution | Small-medium |
Dilute | New minority equity | Moderate dilution | Medium |
Surrender | New majority equity | Change of control | Large |
Rebalance | Asset restructuring | No ownership change, but smaller company | Depends |
Exit | Liquidate | Control ends, break-up value | Final resort |
6๏ธโฃ Second-Order Thinking: What are the risks of the model?
- Illusion of optionality: In reality, many distressed companies are already at Step 3 or 4 before management acts.
- Behavioral traps:
- Existing shareholders often overestimate their willingness to support (Step 1).
- Management may resist Step 3 due to loss of control bias.
- Selling assets selectively (Step 4) may be impossible in time-constrained distress situations.
- Market signaling: Each step sends strong signals to the market, affecting pricing of subsequent steps. For example, a failed rights issue may poison Steps 2 and 3.
7๏ธโฃ Adjacent domain insights:
- Game theory: Each stakeholder is playing a mixed-strategy game. Control, dilution, and survival are in tension.
- Behavioral economics: Loss aversion makes Steps 1 and 3 emotionally difficult. Many boards freeze until Step 4 or 5 is forced.
- Systems thinking: The sequence interacts with external market conditionsโliquidity cycles, asset saleability, and buyer appetite shift the viability of each step.
8๏ธโฃ Summary of recommendations:
Issue | Proposed Enhancement |
---|---|
Linearity of steps | Model it as a decision matrix or branching path, not strictly sequential |
Asset sale logic | Use cash-flow vs strategic value vs marketability rather than “non-productive” vs “non-core” |
Framework positioning | Call it a Capital Salvage or Capital Control Spectrum, not just 5 steps |
Behavioral layer | Add analysis of stakeholder incentives, market signaling, and psychological barriers |